direction des Études et synthèses Économiques g 2008 / 10

48
Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques G 2008 / 10 Who is confronted to insecure labor market histories? Some evidence based on French labor market transitions Magali BEFFY - Élise COUDIN - Roland RATHELOT Document de travail Institut National de la Statistique et des Études Économiques

Upload: others

Post on 17-Jun-2022

1 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques G 2008 / 10

Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques

G 2008 / 10

Who is confronted to insecure labor market histories?

Some evidence based on French labor market transitions

Magali BEFFY - Élise COUDIN - Roland RATHELOT

Document de travail

Institut National de la Statistique et des Études Économiques

Page 2: Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques G 2008 / 10

INSTITUT NATIONAL DE LA STATISTIQUE ET DES ÉTUDES ÉCONOMIQUES

Série des documents de travail de la Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques

NOVEMBRE 2008

We thank Thierry Kamionka and Denis Fougère for their precious help both on technical and practical issues. This work has also benefited from helpful comments from Didier Blanchet, Pascale Breuil, Bruno Crépon, Etienne Debauche, Hélène Erkel-Rousse, Pauline Givord, Guy Laroque, Thomas Le Barbanchon, Thierry Magnac, Antoine Magnier, Sébastien Roux, Béatrice Sédillot and Philippe Zamora. We also thank the participants at the INSEE-DEEE seminar (Malakoff, June 2007), AFSE conference (Paris, September 2007), the INSEE research seminar (Paris, February 2008), the INSEE-DSDS seminar (Paris, March 2008), the CREST-LMi seminar (Malakoff, March 2008), and the ESPE Conference (London, June 2008) for their stimulating comments. All remaining errors are ours. Any opinions expressed here are those of the authors and not of the INSEE.

_____________________________________________

* Direction de l’Évaluation, de la Prospective et de la Performance et Crest

** Faisait partie du Département de l’Emploi et des Revenus d’Activités/INSEE au moment de la rédaction de ce document et Crest

*** Faisait partie du Département des Études Économiques d’Ensemble/INSEE au moment de la rédaction de ce document et Crest

Département des Études Économiques d'Ensemble - Timbre G201 - 15, bd Gabriel Péri - BP 100 - 92244 MALAKOFF CEDEX - France - Tél. : 33 (1) 41 17 60 68 - Fax : 33 (1) 41 17 60 45 - CEDEX - E-mail : [email protected] - Site Web INSEE :

http://www.insee.fr

Ces documents de travail ne reflètent pas la position de l’INSEE et n'engagent que leurs auteurs. Working papers do not reflect the position of INSEE but only their author's views.

G 2008 / 10

Who is confronted to insecure labor market histories?

Some evidence based on French labor market transitions

Magali BEFFY* - Élise COUDIN** - Roland RATHELOT***

Page 3: Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques G 2008 / 10

2

Who is confronted to insecure labor market histories? Some evidence based on the French labor market transitions

Abstract

This paper presents some empirical evidence on the French labor market focusing on transitions between stable jobs, temporary work, unemployment and non-participation. The model used is based on a Markov chain mixture which allows to distinguish labor market histories that are confined to contingent work and non-employment from the non-confined ones. This enables us to identify, quantify and characterize (conditional on observable characteristics) the workers who never accede to stable jobs and remain stuck to temporary jobs and non-employment spells. We consider quarterly labor market transitions, observed from 2003 to 2006 in the Labor Force survey (LFS). We find that on the whole, about 5% of the working age population experience confined transition dynamics: they cannot access to stable jobs. Confined workers are less educated and are more likely to live in distressed areas.

Keywords: labor market mobility, labor market transitions, mover-stayer models, Markov chains

Qui est confronté à des trajectoires précaires sur le marché du travail ?

Quelques enseignements tirés de l’analyse des transitions sur le marché du travail français

Résumé

Cette étude analyse les transitions sur le marché du travail entre quatre états : les périodes d’emploi stable, d’emploi instable, de chômage et d’inactivité. Le modèle utilisé repose sur un mélange de chaînes de Markov et permet de distinguer les individus dont les trajectoires sont confinées entre l’emploi instable et le non-emploi de ceux qui peuvent accéder à un emploi stable. Ceci nous permet de dénombrer et de caractériser en fonction de caractéristiques observables ces travailleurs qui n’accèderont jamais à l’emploi stable. L’estimation repose sur les données trimestrielles de l’enquête Emploi, de 2003 à 2006. Environ 5 % des 30-49 ans ont des trajectoires confinées entre des périodes d’emploi instable et des périodes de non-emploi et ne n’accèderont jamais à un emploi stable. Un très faible niveau d’éducation augmente les risques d’être confiné, habiter en ZUS également.

Mots-clés : mobilité sur le marché du travail, transitions sur le marché du travail, modèles mover-stayer, chaînes de Markov

Classification JEL : J21, J60, C33

Page 4: Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques G 2008 / 10

Contents

1. Introduction 6

2. Data 9

2.1. Summary statistics and representativeness. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10

2.2. Descriptive statistics on transitions. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12

3. Methodology: the conditional confined-unconfined worker model 13

4. Results 16

4.1. Duality in the labor market . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16

4.1.1. The confined movers. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17

4.1.2. The nonparticipant stayers. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18

4.1.3. The stable-job stayers. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19

4.2. Dynamics on the labor market. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19

4.2.1. Confined and unconfined mover transitions. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19

5. Robustness analysis 21

5.1. Heckman-Singer approach. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21

5.2. Specification tests: stability of transition matrices across gender. . . . . . . . . . . . 26

6. Conclusion 27

A. Stationary occupation probabilities 28

B. Darmois-type test for coefficient equality across subsamples 29

C. Detailed results 29

3

Page 5: Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques G 2008 / 10

C.1. Women between 30 and 49. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 29

C.2. Men between 30 and 49. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 30

List of Tables

1 Descriptive statistics. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11

2 Data description. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12

3 Four-State Markov transition matrices. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12

4 Marginal probabilities for each type, given gender and age. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16

5 Average Type-probabilities conditional on initial states. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17

6 Stationary equilibria. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 20

7 Types Distribution. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23

8 Transition matrices according to types. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 25

9 Limiting Probabilities . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 26

10 Tests for stability of dynamics across gender (p-values).. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27

11 Data : women between 30 and 49. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 30

12 Coefficients: women between 30 and 49. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 31

13 Transition matrices: women between 30 and 49. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 32

14 Data : men between 30 and 49. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33

15 Coefficients: men between 30 and 49. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 34

16 Transition matrices: men between 30 and 49. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 35

List of Figures

1 Densities of individual probabilities of being stayer in 1, stayer in 4 and confined condi-

tional on initial states: women between 30 and 49. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 30

4

Page 6: Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques G 2008 / 10

2 Densities of individual probabilities of being stayer in 1, stayer in 4 and confined condi-

tional on initial states: men between 30 and 49. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33

5

Page 7: Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques G 2008 / 10

1. Introduction

Flexible employment has drastically increased in France since the introductionof short-term contracts

(Contrats à Durée Déterminée, CDD) and temporary work (mission d’intérim) in the early 1980’s.

Short-term contracts represent 66% of hirings in 2005 while 60% of the transitions from employment to

non-employment concern a short-term job ending. These flexible devices, which may be justified by the

need to maintain the competitiveness of the firms, induce a higher frequency of labor market transitions.

The transition rate between employment and nonemployment has significantly increased between 1975

and 2000 (Behaghel, 2003). Risks of involuntary job loss were higher inthe 1990’s than in the 1980’s

(Givord and Maurin, 2003). In this context, studying transitions on the labor market and the distribution

of mobilities within the workforce is of first interest.

The nature of the job contract occupies an important place in the French debate on labor market and

labor legislation. The controversy on the "Contrat Unique", following those on the "Contrat Nouvelle

Embauche" (CNE) and the "Contrat Première Embauche" (CPE) in 2005 and 2006, stressed indeed that

the nature of the job contract is a crucial feature of job quality.1 Then, it is interesting to distinguish job

spells in long-term contract and job spells in short-term contract. Hence, Four states stand out on the

French labor market: stable employment, which contains long-term contract jobs and self-employed;

contingent work, which refers to short-term contracts and temporary orseasonal jobs; unemployment

and nonparticipation. The scope of this paper is to analyze and quantify thedifferent kinds of labor

market histories entailed by the transition dynamics between those states.

Short-term jobs may be a stepping stone in an integration process or a trap intoinsecurity. The

economic literature supports both aspects. On the one hand, theories of imperfect information (Spence,

1973), transaction costs (Williamson, 1975) and insider-outsider (Lindbeck and Snower, 1986, 2002)

give some explanations of a dual labor market which either rely on the heterogeneity of the labor supply

1On the one hand, the pros of a "Contrat Unique" advocate for standardizing the multiple kinds of jobs contract in a singleform. On the other hand, in recent years, the government made two attempts to introduce new forms of job contracts: the CNE,introduced in August 2005, was a long-term contract with simplified and lightened termination rules only available for firmswith at most 20 employees; the CPE was an attempt of generalization of the CNE available only for young workers (under26). These two attempts aborted: the CPE was canceled due to tough demonstrations in spring 2007; the CNE was declaredunconstitutional just two years after its introduction.

6

Page 8: Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques G 2008 / 10

productivity or on the existence of negotiation power in a context of imperfect information.2 These

theories stress the role of signalling in perpetuating a vicious circle. Employers may consider a long

history through unemployment and contingent work as a bad signal on a worker’s ability and then

they may offer him or her insecure positions rather secure ones (Katz, 1986).3 Further, Cahuc and

Postel-Vinay (2002) and Blanchard and Landier (2002) relate the labormarket duality to the coexistence

of short-term jobs and highly protected long-term ones. Besides, theories of segmented labor markets

stress the outstanding role of firms in shaping the labor market duality with the existence of internal

labor markets and human resources’ management or human capital investment which differ according

to the job sector; see for instance the seminal work of Doeringher and Piore (1971). On the other

hand, temporary jobs, more precisely short job spells, can be viewed as opportunities, especially for

young workers, to accumulate general human capital. Temporary job spellsmay also provide a worker

with enough time and/or information to find out the best firm match; see Burdett (1978), Jovanovic

(1979a, 1979b), Mortensen (1988), Topel and Ward (1992).

Cross-sectional studies on labor market duality (see L’Horty, 2004, Gazier and Petit, 2007) do not

take into account the (complete) labor market histories. Here, we adopt a totally different strategy.

The identification of the duality structure relies only on the observed transitions between the different

positions/states on the labor market. More precisely, we use a mover-stayerapproach (Blumen, Kogan,

and MacCarthy, 1955, Kamionka, 1996), which distinguishes workers who remain stuck to contingent

work (typically those alternating nonemployment spells with short-term jobs) from those who may

access to stable jobs and benefit in a sense from an integration process.The approach proposed is

conditional on individual characteristics, which extends Kamionka (1996). Hence, this method enables

us to separate labor market histories which are confined to contingent work and non-employment from

those which are not and to characterize the individuals who experience them.

The discrete time mover-stayer model was first introduced by Blumen, Kogan, and MacCarthy (1955)

to study industrial mobility on the labor market; see also Anderson and Goodman(1957), Goodman

(1961), Spilerman (1972), Singer and Spilerman (1976) and Frydman (1984). This model relies on a

2Lindbeck and Snower (1986, 2002) summarize theoretical breakthroughs and list key references.3Blanchard and Landier (2002) provide some semantic advice: whereas the French have a specific word designating a

succession of short-term jobs and unemployment spells (précarité), there does not exist an equivalent expression in English.We follow Blanchard and Landier’s suggestion to useinsecurityinstead.

7

Page 9: Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques G 2008 / 10

mixture of Markov chains which accounts for different dynamic patterns among individuals. Its most

basic version assumes that two kinds of workers coexist on the labor market: while themoverscan move

from unemployment to employment, thestayersremain indefinitely in the state they initially occupy.4

In the version proposed by Kamionka (1996), some workers, namedunconfined movers, can have

access to any kind of jobs whereas some others, calledconfined movers, can only transit between

unemployment, short-term jobs and non-participation. The introduction of different individual types

allows one to account for the so-called partially observed heterogeneity.We use the same partition

but we explicitly let the mixture probabilities (being a mover, confined or unconfined, or being a

stayer) depend on observed characteristics (conditional confined-unconfined model). This allows us

to investigate which individual characteristics are correlated with specific dynamic patterns on the

labor market. In other words, the version that we propose enables us to highlight who the stayers, the

unconfined movers and the confined movers are. Further, the share ofunconfined moversin the economy

and amongst the movers may provide an indicator of the labor market duality level.

Apart from the mover-stayer models, labor market transitions are usually studied using discrete

choice models and/or duration models.Discrete-choice modelsexplain the individual status given

his/her past (and notably his/her past status) and covariates; see for instance Card and Sullivan (1988),

Magnac (2000) or Havet (2006).Duration modelsexplain the duration of a spell in a given state by

the past and a set of individual characteristics; see for example in the French labor market context,

Bonnal, Fougère, and Sérandon (1997) and Magnac and Robin (1994). Duration models capture state

and duration dependence whereas Markov-chain-based approaches account for state dependence and

partially observed heterogeneity. So our study completes previous studiesof the French labor market by

focusing on partially observed heterogeneity.

The discrete time mover-stayer-type model proposed in this paper aims to separate histories when

individuals never accede to stable jobs from histories when individuals have a potential access to both

unstable and stable jobs. The population who experiences confined moverhistories is of first interest

for policy concerns. Moreover, a statistical approachà la Heckman and Singer (1984), which does not

4Mover-stayer models have also been adapted to continuous time Fougèreand Kamionka (1992a, 1992b, 2003, 2008) suchas other Markov chain models Kalbfleish and Lawless (1985), Geweke,Marshall, and Zarkin (1986a, 1986b).

8

Page 10: Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques G 2008 / 10

require toa priori impose the nature of types and zero-constraints on the transition matrix components,

does not reject the relevance of the partition postulated here. In this alternative approach, the form and

the number of the transition matrices are let free but more structure is imposed on the state dependence.

Transitions are actually modeled by a dynamic multinomial logit with unobserved heterogeneity - which

entails restrictions; see Magnac (2000) and Brodaty (2007).

The model is estimated by maximum likelihood on a sample composed of 30-49 yearsold people who

finished their studies. The data come from the French Labor Force Survey. We focus on middle-aged

people to avoid life-cycle effects that may violate stationarity requirements of Markov Chain models

(labor market entrance of youth, retiring). Our main findings are the following. Individuals trapped into

confined mover histories represent about5% of the total population. This is much less than the13%

computed in summary statistics, showing the relevance of our model to handle heavily censored data.

Individuals falling into theconfined-movercategory are more likely to be less educated, younger and

single. At stationary equilibrium,30% of them occupy unstable jobs, nearly one half are unemployed,

while the remaining do not participate.

The paper is organized as follows. The data and summary statistics are presented in section 2, and the

model in section 3. Section 4 is dedicated to the estimation results. Section 5 contains the results of the

Heckman-Singer approach and some specification tests. Section 6 concludes.

2. Data

The data come from the French Labor Force survey (LFS), 2003-2007, undertaken by Insee, the French

national statistical office. The LFS is a rolling panel in which individuals areinterviewed on their labor

market status, once per quarter, six times. This scheme enables one to construct individual labor market

histories over 15 months. Each quarter, one surveyed individual out of six is replaced. In this paper, we

use the LFS answers of the 30-49 years old individuals who entered the survey from 2003Q1 to 2005Q4,

who finished their studies and who were interviewed 6 times. This panel consists in 33,206 individuals.

The LFS contains information on labor market states - employment, unemploymentand nonparticipation

- as well as a detailed description of the job occupied by the employed. Long-term contracts, short-term

9

Page 11: Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques G 2008 / 10

contracts, temporary jobs, internships are distinguished. In what follows, we consider four labor market

states: nonparticipation (NP), unemployment (U), unstable job state (UJ) which contains public and

private short-term contracts, temporary jobs and seasonal jobs, and astable job state (SJ) which contains

private long-term contracts, self-employed and civil-servant positions. Unemployment refers to the ILO

definition: unemployed are nonemployed, available to work within two weeks and actively search for a

job. So, non-employed who search for a job are classified as nonparticipants if they do not satisfy the

availability criterion.5 Finally, the panel contains information on individual characteristics, age,gender,

educational level, residential location, family characteristics, etc..

2.1. Summary statistics and representativeness

First, we briefly describe the current French labor market. In 2006, theaverage participation rate

amounted to69% for 15-64 years old,74.5% for men and63.8% for women; see Attal-Toubert and

Lavergne (2006). The French labor market is characterized by a weak participation rate of youth and the

oldest compared to other European countries. This feature is often linkedto the fact that in the 1980’s and

the 1990’s the government and social partners answered to a growing mass unemployment by promoting

early retirements and longer studies. In 2006, around10% of the 15-64 participants were unemployed,

nearly half of them having been unemployed for more than one year.6 Higher unemployment risk is

correlated with: a low level of education, youth, female gender, and blue-collar occupation.13.5%

of the employed occupied an unstable job that is training, apprenticeship, fixed-duration or temporary

contract jobs.

We focus on 30-49 years old people who finished their studies, becausewe are interested in rather

stable labor market histories, once integration is completed and before the retirement process begins.

Furthermore, we ensure stationarity of underlying processes by concentrating on individuals aged be-

tween 30 and 49. The descriptive statistics assessed on the panel data onthe one hand, and on the

pooled LFS 2003Q1-2007Q1 on the other hand, are quite close; see Table 1. Nonetheless, a slight under-

representation of men and of unemployed people can be observed in the balanced panel. This is due

5See Jones and Riddel (2006) for a deep analysis of the frontiers between nonparticipation and ILO unemployment; see alsoFlinn and Heckman (1983).

6The definition of unemployment and the estimation method of the unemployment rate changed in 2007 in France. Thedefinition used here is the one prevailing before 2007.

10

Page 12: Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques G 2008 / 10

to attrition. Unemployed people usually move more often and they are less likely to be interviewed six

times. The results presented in the sequel are those holding for the panel.

Table 1. Descriptive statistics

Panel subsample LFS whole sample*(obs. 33,206× 6) (obs. 395,077)

(30-49 years old)(Studies finished)

Population% women 52.3 50.4

% men 47.8 49.6Participation rate %

Women 81.2 82.3Men 95.6 95.4Total 88.1 88.8

Unemployment rate %Women 7.5 7.8

Men 5.8 6.4Total 6.7 7.1

Employment rate %Women 73.7 74.5

Men 89.9 88.9Total 81.4 81.7

Share of long-term contracts %Women 86.2 86.2

Men 92.9 91.5Total 89.8 89.1

* pooled analysis.

11

Page 13: Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques G 2008 / 10

2.2. Descriptive statistics on transitions

The transitions between nonparticipation, unemployment, unstable jobs and stable jobs observed in the

balanced panel are described in Table 2. First,75% of the sample sojourn within long-term jobs or do

not participate during the whole observation period, while only25% experience in-sample transitions.

Second, 19% of men and 27% of women experience one or more transition within the observation period.

Half of them accede to a long-term contract job and half of them transit without acceding to a CDI. So the

apparent ratio of individuals trapped into "contingent work" is 9% for menand 15% for women. Labor

market histories greatly differ between men and women. Women are more likely tobe nonparticipant

during the whole observation period than men (13% versus 20%) and men are more likely to occupy a

stable job during the whole observation period.

Table 2. Data description

Men WomenIndividuals... 15,847 100% 17,359 100%sojourning in long-term jobs 12,497 79% 10,495 60 %staying nonparticipants 382 2% 2,188 13%moving between long-term, short-term jobs and without job spells 1,571 10% 2,065 12%moving between short-term jobs and without job spells only 1,397 9% 2,611 15%

A simple Markov-chain model also provides some insightful summary statistics, see Table 3.

Table 3. Four-state Markov transition matrices

MenT → T + 1 SJ UJ U NPSJ 0.989 0.002 0.005 0.004

(0.000)* (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)UJ 0.084 0.759 0.128 0.029

(0.004) (0.008) (0.007) (0.003)U 0.067 0.147 0.696 0.090

(0.004) (0.006) (0.008) (0.004)NP 0.074 0.024 0.112 0.791

(0.005) (0.003) (0.006) (0.009)

WomenSJ UJ U NP0.983 0.003 0.005 0.009(0.001) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)0.062 0.785 0.113 0.040(0.003) (0.007) (0.005) (0.002)0.059 0.136 0.669 0.137(0.003) (0.004) (0.006) (0.005)0.037 0.016 0.059 0.887(0.002) (0.001) (0.002) (0.003)

* bootstrapped standard deviations with 50 replicates.

Stable jobs and nonparticipation are the most persistent states:99% and79% of persistence within

three months for men, and98% and89% for women. Around75% of workers with unstable jobs and

12

Page 14: Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques G 2008 / 10

66% of unemployed remain in the same state three months later.

The propensity to accede to stable jobs is more state-dependent for women than for men.6.7% of

male unemployed,8.4% of male temporary workers and7.4% of male nonparticipants obtain a stable

job within three months whereas5.9% of female unemployed,6.2% of female temporary workers and

only 3.7% of female nonparticipants obtain a stable job within three months. Female nonparticipants are

further away from the labor market than men are.

About 75% of unemployed individuals, whether male or female, transit to employment via a tempo-

rary job (15% versus6% for stable jobs). On the one hand, this underlines the potentially integrating

nature of temporary jobs. Before finding a long-term job, a large part ofthe unemployed go through

temporary jobs. On the other hand, this may also suggest a dual labor market. Unemployed people have

more frequently access to unstable jobs rather than to stable positions. The relationship between unem-

ployment and non-participation is asymmetric for women:14% of the unemployed leave the labor force

each quarter, whereas only6% of the non-participants become unemployed. For men, these proportions

are quite the same:9% of male unemployed exit the labor force,11% of male nonparticipants become

unemployed.

3. Methodology: the conditional confined-unconfined worker model

The former Markov-chain model assumes that labor market transitions aregenerated by the same

underlying process for all individuals. This approach is restrictive in that it does not provide information

on coexisting different dynamic processes. To cover a potential labor market heterogeneity, we turn

to mover-stayer-like models. Mover-stayer models rely on a mixture of Markov chains; see Blumen,

Kogan, and MacCarthy (1955), Goodman (1961), Spilerman (1972), Singer and Spilerman (1976),

Frydman (1984). The model developed in this section extends the version of Kamionka (1996)

Let us considerN individualsi = 1, . . . , N , observed at datest = 0, . . . , T . These individuals can

transit betweenK states relating to their labor market situation (K = 4 in what follows) -stable jobs(1),

short-term jobs(2), unemployment(3) andnonparticipation(4). The individuali experiences a sequence

of states denoted by theT -vector(ei0, . . . , eiT ). Ci denotes the kind of dynamic process generating the

13

Page 15: Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques G 2008 / 10

transitions experienced by individuali. Four dynamic processes are assumed to exist:stable-job stayer

(S1), nonparticipant stayer(SK), unconfined mover(M ), confined mover(I). The twostayerprocesses

generate histories sojourning indefinitely in the same state and the twomoverprocesses generate histories

with transitions.

• The unconfined-moverprocess corresponds to labor-market histories where individuals canac-

cess to any of theK states, and in particular to stable jobs. Those histories are associated to an

unconstrained Markov chain with transition matrixM = {mij}.

• The confined-moverprocess corresponds to labor-market histories where workers cannot have

access to stable jobs. Formally, the underlying stochastic process is a degenerated Markov chain

with transition matrixQ = {qij}, in which the row and the column components related to the

stable-job state are set to zero.

Furthermore, individuali is endowed with characteristicsXi. The dynamic heterogeneity which is

taken into account by the random variableCi is not observed but is assumed to depend on observables.7

Then,

• pS1(Xi) is the probability to be a stayer in stable jobs (state 1), conditional on starting in state1

and covariatesXi;

• pSK(Xi) is the probability to be a stayer out of the labor market (stateK) , conditional on starting

in stateK and covariatesXi;

• pI(Xi) is the probability to be a confined mover, conditional on not starting in state1 and covariates

Xi, i.e., whether the individual starts in state2, 3, . . . , or K.

The contribution of individuali to the likelihood conditional on the initial state depends on the ob-

served history.

1. When individuali is observed to start in state1, stable job, alternatives cases may occur.

If a transition is observed during the observation period, individuali is, for sure, an unconfined

7Kamionka (1996) describes this dynamic heterogeneity as a partially observed heterogeneity since the labor market histo-ries, partially observed, provide information on the individual types, in contrast with other unobserved individual heterogeneitymethods.

14

Page 16: Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques G 2008 / 10

mover. His or her contribution to the likelihood is thus:

(

1 − pS1(Xi)

)

T∏

t=1

mit−1it .

If no transition is observed, individuali may either be a stayer in state1 or an unconfined mover.

His/her contribution is:

pS1(Xi) +

(

1 − pS1(Xi)

)

T∏

t=1

mit−1it .

2. When individuali starts in states2 or 3, there are also two options.

If individual i occupies a stable job at least once, then he or she is an unconfined mover. His or her

contribution is:

(1 − pI(Xi))T

t=1

mit−1it .

If individual i does not occupy a stable job during the observation period, then he or she may either

be a confined mover or an unconfined mover. His or her contribution is:

pI(Xi)T

t=1

qit−1it + (1 − pI(Xi))T

t=1

mit−1it .

3. When individuali starts by a nonparticipation spell, three cases may occur.

If individual i occupies once a stable job, then he or she is an unconfined mover. His or her

contribution is:

(1 − pSK(Xi))(1 − pI(Xi))

T∏

t=1

mit−1it .

When individuali does not occupy a stable job during the period, then he or she may be a confined

mover or an unconfined mover. His or her contribution is:

(1 − pSK(Xi))

[

pI(Xi)T

t=1

qit−1it + (1 − pI(Xi))T

t=1

mit−1it

]

.

If individual i remains in stateK, then he or she may be stayer, confined mover or unconfined

mover. His or her contribution is:

pSK(Xi) + (1 − pSK

(Xi))

[

pI(Xi)T

t=1

qit−1it + (1 − pI(Xi))T

t=1

mit−1it

]

.

15

Page 17: Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques G 2008 / 10

Finally, the conditional likelihood is the product of theN individual contributions. The model is

identified if the number of periods of observation is at least3. The identification relies on the fact that

the stayer transition matrices are set to be the identity matrix and that the individuals who move at least

once in the stable job state are known to be unconfined movers. If they are observed at least three times,

they are supposed to experience the4×4 kinds of transitions, which enables the identification. The model

is estimated by a standard maximum likelihood method. For a more detailed discussionon identification

and consistency of ML estimators, see Kamionka (1996) and Frydman (1984). In practice, the model

is reparameterized to take into account that, in the transition matrices, the exit probabilities belong to

[0, 1] and sum to one by row. The conditional probabilities of being of a given type are modeled by logit

models.

4. Results

The conditional confined-unconfined model is estimated separately on men and women, in order to take

into account gender heterogeneity of labor market dynamics. This approach is justified by a specification

analysis presented in section 5.2.8 The covariates used to explain the conditional probabilities of being

of a given kind are the following: age, marital status, having children, education, residence location (in

Paris region vs. outside, in a distressed area (ZUS) vs. outside). In what follows, a discussion of the

main results is presented. The detailed figures are reported in Appendix C (see Tables 11-15 and Figures

1 and 2).

4.1. Duality in the labor market

First, table 4 reports the probabilities that a worker is of one of the four types.

Table 4. Marginal probabilities for each type, given gender and age.

stayer unconfined confined stayer outin stable job mover mover of the labor market

Women 30-49 51.0% 32.1% 5.2% 11.7%Men 30-49 70.6% 22.5% 4.3% 2.5%

8In section 5.2, we investigate whether the labor market dynamics can be modeled by the same processes for both gender.Tests confirm that transition matrices differ across gender groups.

16

Page 18: Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques G 2008 / 10

Around 63% of women and 73% of men are stayers, either in stable jobs or out of the labor market,

while the remaining are movers. Confined movers are around 5% of the wholepopulation, but around

15% of the movers.

The 5% figure of confined movers has to be compared to the empirical ratio ofconfined movers found

without accounting for truncation, which amounts to 13% [Tables 11 and 14].9 So the model structure is

successful in controlling for the truncation induced by the 15 months of observation.

Table 5. Average Type-probabilities conditional on initial states

confined stayer in nonparticipant % confinedmover stable job stayer movers|2,3,4

Women 30-49 0.153 0.771 0.610 23%(0.033) (0.014) (0.012)

Men 30-49 0.285 0.832 0.546 36%(0.043) (0.012) (0.018)

* st. errors obtained by bootstrap, using 100 sample replicates.

Table 5 reports the marginal probabilities of being of a given type conditional on the initial state. This

table sums up the last rows of tables 12 and 15 for readability.

4.1.1. The confined movers

The confined-mover population keeps on alternating nonemployment spells with short-term jobs

without being able to accede to a stable position. The confined-mover labor-market histories concern

approximately 29% of the 30-49 men and 15% of the 30-49 women who do not start in a stable job

[Table 5].

Figures 1 and 2 report the densities of the individual probabilities of beingof a given type estimated

on the sample. Their spread provides some insight about the way the included covariates explain the

propensity of being of that type. In a sense it gives an indication on the goodness-of-fit of the model.

When the covariates are poor predictors, the distributions of the predictedprobabilities are expected to

peak around the mean value. Here, on the contrary, they stretch over[0, 1], which indicates that a notable

part of the heterogeneity is explained by the observables.

9i.e., the share of people that never reach stable jobs during the 15 months observed.

17

Page 19: Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques G 2008 / 10

The effects of the covariates on the probability of being a confined mover are reported in the first

column of Tables 13 and 16. Education is the only relevant variable we find toexplain females probability

to be confined movers: lower degrees tend to be correlated with higher probabilities. Not surprisingly,

for males, education is relevant as well. But family variables also enter significantly: men with lower

probabilities to be confined movers are more likely to be married and to have children. They are also less

likely to live in more distressed areas (ZUS).

4.1.2. The nonparticipant stayers

55% of men who were initially out of the labor market are nonparticipant stayers versus62% for women

(table 5). This illustrates the fact that French women are further from the labor market than are men.

After a nonparticipation spell, women are more likely to stay nonparticipant thanmen; after a long-term

job spell, they are more likely to move to short-term jobs or nonemployment.

The effects of the covariates on the probability of being stayers out of thelabor market are reported in

the third column of tables 13 and 16. Non participants stayers are rather older (being over than forty is

significant for both gender groups), and less educated. However, the degree stratification does not look

the same across groups. Among men, the distinction is between having a degree or no degree at all: the

quality of the degree is not correlated with the probability to stay out of the labor force. Among women,

on the other hand, there seems to exist a strict hierarchy in degrees: women with university degree are

less likely to be non participant than high school graduates, who themselvesare less likely than women

with some elementary or no degree at all. For men, having children is correlated with lower probabilities

to be non participants. The effect of children is more complex for women. Ofcourse, having a 0 to 3

year old child is correlated with higher probabilities to stay our of the labor market. However, having

a 4 to 6 years old child is correlated with lower probabilities to stay our of the labor market. The fact

of being married and living outside the Paris regions are two characteristicsof women who are further

away from the labor market. These results illustrate that family variables affect the female labor market

histories and dynamics whereas their impacts are smaller and more subtle on male ones. They directly

refer to the traditional separation of roles between men and women.

18

Page 20: Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques G 2008 / 10

4.1.3. The stable-job stayers

Between 30 and 49,83% of men starting in stable jobs are stayers in stable jobs versus77% of women.

The education level has a noticeable impact both for women and for men. Having no degree or a basic

vocational degree seriously reduces the chances of being a stayer in stable jobs. Then, age has a strong

positive effect, indicating that older workers enjoy more stable histories. Adistressed local labor market

has a significant negative impact: living in a ZUS reduces the probability of being a stayer in a stable job

both for 30-49 men and women. Finally, family variables have some, yet less important than for other

probabilities, impact on the probability of being a stayer in stable jobs. Being married is more frequent

for men who are stayers in stable jobs. As expected, having a child aged 0 to6 is correlated with not

being a stayer in a stable jobs.

4.2. Dynamics on the labor market

Four different processes generating labor market transitions are estimated. Two of them are stayer

processes. People experiencing them remain indefinitely in their initial state,i.e. nonparticipation or

long-term job. The two other processes generate labor market transitions. The unconfined-mover process

generates histories in which individuals can access to the four states without restriction. The confined-

mover process generates histories in which individuals cannot access tostable jobs. In this section, the

estimated dynamics are compared.

4.2.1. Confined and unconfined mover transitions

The unconfined-mover-transition process and the confined-mover-transition process clearly describe

different labor market histories. The unconfined-mover-transition process generates histories which refer

much more often to employment states than the confined-mover-transition one. This holds whatever the

gender category.

Table 6 reports the stationary occupation probabilities for each state depending on the underlying

dynamic. This table sums up the results of tables 13 and 16.

A given woman (resp. man) in unconfined-mover dynamics is in employment atthe stationary

19

Page 21: Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques G 2008 / 10

Table 6. Stationary equilibria

Unconfined equilibrium Confined equilibriumSJ UJ U UNP UJ U UNP

Women 30-49 0.585 0.143 0.134 0.1380.299 0.403 0.297(0.023) (0.009) (0.011) (0.013) (0.059) (0.044) (0.069)

Men 30-49 0.680 0.143 0.122 0.055 0.289 0.541 0.169(0.026) (0.012) (0.014) (0.006) (0.054) (0.042) (0.032)

*bootstrap standard errors using 100 sample replicates

equilibrium with a probability of 73% (resp. 82%). For a woman (resp. man) inconfined-dynamics,

this probability is only 30% (resp. 29%). Therefore, being employed is twiceas likely for individuals

in unconfined dynamics than for those in confined ones. Furthermore, theunconfined-mover-transition

process generates histories which refer slightly more often to participation than the confined-mover one.

At equilibrium, unconfined males (resp. females) are 94% (resp. 86%) to participate, versus 83% (resp.

70%) of confined males (females).

These results suggest that the main part of the difference between the unconfined and the confined-

mover dynamics cannot be explained by an underlying difference in participation behaviors. This

difference is rather explained by the fact that people in confined-moverdynamics more often experience

difficult episodes on the labor market such as unemployment than people in unconfined-mover dynamics.

This is obvious when the unemployment probability is examined (around 12% for unconfined movers

versus 40% to 54% for confined movers).

The parameters in transition matrices stress the unemployment risk faced by individuals with

confined-mover histories. Around 30% of individuals initially in unstable jobsand with a confined-

mover dynamic would experience unemployment three months later versus around 7% of those with

unconfined-mover dynamics. 38% of nonparticipant men with a confined-mover history would become

unemployed three months later versus 20% of those with a unconfined-moverhistory. These remarks

hold also for women.

The male and the female unconfined-mover dynamics are significantly different, as shown by speci-

fication tests. Men in confined dynamics tend to be less mobile than women and display, for example,

20

Page 22: Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques G 2008 / 10

higher persistence in unemployment. The picture is rather different for unconfined dynamics. Uncon-

fined males are more mobile than women and they more often get access to employment, both to stable

and unstable jobs.

5. Robustness analysis

5.1. Heckman-Singer approach

In mover-stayer-type models, the form of the heterogeneity is imposedex anteby the model (i.e., stayers,

unconfined movers, confined movers). In this section, we adopt an alternative model, which does not

require to fixa priori the nature of types and constraints on transition matrices, in order to see whether

the entailed partition shares common features with the one we proposed. We follow the approach of

Brodaty (2007) which is inspired by Magnac (2000) and Heckman and Singer (1984). Transitions are

modeled by a dynamic multinomial logit with unobserved heterogeneity. Letyit denote the labor market

state occupied by the individuali at datet, then

yit = k if only if y∗ikt = maxj=1,...,4

(y∗ijt), ∀(i, t), (5.1)

where

y∗ijt =

4∑

j=1

δjkIyi,t−1=j + αik + ǫikt, ∀(i, t). (5.2)

δjk’s account for dependence from the lag state (state dependence),αik’s is the unobserved hetero-

geneity term. This unobserved propensity to move from one state to another istype-specific,i.e.

αi = (αi1, . . . , αi4)′ can takeT different values,α1, . . . , αT , whereT is the number of types present in

the model. In order to identify the model, some parameters are set to 0:

δj4 = 0,∀j = 1, . . . , 4,

δ4j = 0,∀j = 1, . . . , 4,

αl4 = 0,∀l = 1, . . . , T.

Further, theǫ’s are type-I extreme value distributed, independent across alternatives, individuals, time

and independent of theα’s. Then, the probability that individuali goes to statek at timet conditional on

21

Page 23: Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques G 2008 / 10

being in statej at t − 1 is given by

P (yit = k|yit−1 = j, αi = αl) =exp(δjk + αik)

∑4m=1 exp(δjm + αim)

. (5.3)

It depends on his unobserved typel. Contrary to mover-stayer model, noa priori 0-constraints are

imposed on the transition matrix components, but the dynamic multinomial logit model implies that the

odds ratios satisfy the following constraints:

P(SJ |State=k,Type=l)P(SJ |State=j,Type=l)

P(UJ |State=k,Type=l)P(UJ |State=j,Type=l)

=

P(SJ |State=k,Type=l′)P(SJ |State=j,Type=l′)

P(UJ |State=k,Type=l′)P(UJ |State=j,Type=l′)

, ∀(j, k, l, l′). (5.4)

Finally, there is no reason why the dynamic multinomial logit model would be more orless flexible than

the mover-stayer approach.

This model is estimated sequentially. The first step consists in a conditional maximum likelihood

estimation that yields consistent estimates of the state dependence parameters.The type-specific terms

are estimated in a second step using an EM algorithm, given the first-stage estimates. The number of

types is determined iteratively. The initial condition problem is tackled by using alikelihood conditional

on initial states (Brodaty, 2007). Hence, the probability of being of typer depends on the individual

initial state. The number of types is determined iteratively.

For men as well as for women, the iterative procedure suggests to retain a partition in five categories.

Table 7 details the probabilities of these five types conditional on the four possible initial states. Women

who are initially out of the labor force have a high probability to be type-1 individuals (60%) or type-5

individuals (28%). Probabilities for men are not as clear cut: when they start out of the labor force,

they tend to be type-1 (57%) and type-5 (18%), but also of type-2 and type-4 (11% each). Almost all

individuals starting in stable jobs are type-2. Conditional on starting in unstable jobs, men are mainly

type-3 (84%) and type-4 (13%). Women, apart from type-3 (83%) andtype-4 (10%) are, in fewer cases,

type-5 (6%). Finally, the types of men and women starting in unemployment are similarly distributed:

mainly type-4 (around 65%), then type-3 (around 20%) and type-5 (around 15%).

Table 8 contains the estimates of the transition matrices associated to each type. These matrices and

22

Page 24: Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques G 2008 / 10

Table 7. Types Distribution

Initial StateWomen SJ UJ U NPType 1 0.002

(0.001)0.000(0.003)

0.009(0.007)

0.601(0.024)

Type 2 0.907(0.009)

0.019(0.008)

0.011(0.007)

0.044(0.005)

Type 3 0.020(0.004)

0.831(0.018)

0.220(0.017)

0.024(0.003)

Type 4 0.018(0.003)

0.094(0.013)

0.611(0.021)

0.056(0.007)

Type 5 0.053(0.010)

0.056(0.013)

0.148(0.020)

0.275(0.024)

Initial StateMen SJ UJ U NP

Type 1 0.000(0.001)

0.010(0.004)

0.000(0.004)

0.572(0.031)

Type 2 0.925(0.013)

0.020(0.009)

0.000(0.002)

0.106(0.018)

Type 3 0.025(0.004)

0.839(0.052)

0.207(0.026)

0.030(0.010)

Type 4 0.015(0.004)

0.131(0.017)

0.657(0.037)

0.114(0.025)

Type 5 0.035(0.012)

0.000(0.049)

0.136(0.029)

0.179(0.044)

Note: Each column sums to one. Standard er-rors are reported in parentheses.

the heterogeneity distribution have to be analyzed together. They are usedto give an interpretation of

the individual types that were found and to compare them with the types imposed in the mover-stayer

approach. Standard errors are obtained by bootstrap using 70 replicates. Table 9 contains the stationary

occupation probabilities for each type.

• Type-1 transition matrix exhibits high transition probabilities to non-participation.Moreover, in-

dividuals who are initially out of the labor market are mainly of type-1. Thesetwo points enable

us to interpret quite unambiguously type-1- individual as “stayers out ofthe labor market”.

• The same kind of argument can be used to assert that individuals followingtype-2 process are

“stayers in stable jobs”.

• The three last types are more intricate. Individuals of type-3 are often in unstable jobs. They have

low conditional probabilities to accede to a stable job whatever their departing state: less than

10% when they have an unstable job the period before, and even lower for women (6%) than for

men (9%); between 8% and 13% when they come from unemployment or non-participation. Thus,

individuals of type-3 are close to confined movers.

23

Page 25: Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques G 2008 / 10

• Type-4 individuals are mainly unemployed. When they get exit unemployment,they are more

likely to find unstable jobs if they are male (10%) and to exit the labor market if they are female

(8%). Their probability to exit unemployment obtaining a stable job is very low around 5%, both

for men and for women. Further, obtaining a stable job is unlikely, whatever the departing state:

the transition probabilities never exceed 10%. And this holds also for men andwomen. Type 4 is

the closest to the confined mover-type.

• Finally, type-5 individuals have relatively strong probabilities to accede to astable job, whatever

the state they start in (around 25% for men, and 15% for women). However, they almost never pass

through unstable job or unemployment spells. They obviously can be interpreted as unconfined

movers.

24

Page 26: Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques G 2008 / 10

Table 8. Transition matrices according to types

Men

First type

0.243(0.129)

0.006(0.002)

0.010(0.004)

0.741(0.129)

0.031(0.028)

0.074(0.028)

0.024(0.013)

0.871(0.046)

0.015(0.013)

0.019(0.007)

0.034(0.019)

0.931(0.029)

0.006(0.005)

0.005(0.002)

0.009(0.004)

0.980(0.007)

Second type

0.998(0.000)

0.000(0.000)

0.001(0.000)

0.001(0.000)

0.950(0.018)

0.032(0.016)

0.011(0.004)

0.008(0.004)

0.933(0.024)

0.017(0.009)

0.033(0.015)

0.017(0.008)

0.924(0.031)

0.011(0.006)

0.020(0.009)

0.044(0.023)

Third type

0.856(0.022)

0.079(0.016)

0.046(0.007)

0.019(0.004)

0.086(0.009)

0.810(0.008)

0.086(0.006)

0.018(0.003)

0.103(0.016)

0.534(0.028)

0.316(0.025)

0.048(0.009)

0.132(0.029)

0.454(0.046)

0.254(0.029)

0.161(0.028)

Fourth type

0.710(0.046)

0.027(0.006)

0.213(0.039)

0.050(0.010)

0.089(0.017)

0.346(0.029)

0.507(0.026)

0.058(0.012)

0.046(0.007)

0.097(0.007)

0.790(0.013)

0.067(0.008)

0.058(0.013)

0.083(0.013)

0.635(0.039)

0.224(0.039)

Fifth type

0.902(0.033)

0.002(0.018)

0.029(0.013)

0.068(0.016)

0.399(0.083)

0.083(0.113)

0.243(0.041)

0.275(0.061)

0.221(0.052)

0.025(0.067)

0.411(0.048)

0.343(0.062)

0.159(0.039)

0.012(0.056)

0.185(0.039)

0.645(0.072)

Women

First type

0.000(0.065)

0.000(0.001)

0.005(0.003)

0.995(0.066)

0.000(0.010)

0.000(0.008)

0.009(0.007)

0.991(0.019)

0.000(0.005)

0.000(0.002)

0.014(0.010)

0.986(0.015)

0.000(0.002)

0.000(0.000)

0.003(0.002)

0.997(0.004)

Second type

0.998(0.001)

0.000(0.000)

0.000(0.000)

0.001(0.000)

0.956(0.016)

0.021(0.013)

0.010(0.004)

0.014(0.005)

0.940(0.019)

0.009(0.006)

0.026(0.011)

0.025(0.009)

0.921(0.024)

0.006(0.004)

0.014(0.006)

0.058(0.021)

Third type

0.804(0.029)

0.108(0.020)

0.060(0.009)

0.028(0.004)

0.059(0.004)

0.828(0.007)

0.089(0.004)

0.024(0.002)

0.082(0.011)

0.512(0.022)

0.344(0.019)

0.062(0.006)

0.105(0.014)

0.457(0.027)

0.244(0.016)

0.194(0.019)

Fourth type

0.726(0.032)

0.023(0.004)

0.196(0.026)

0.054(0.008)

0.094(0.014)

0.312(0.024)

0.513(0.023)

0.082(0.010)

0.052(0.004)

0.077(0.006)

0.788(0.009)

0.006(0.028)

0.070(0.010)

0.072(0.007)

0.585(0.022)

0.273(0.023)

Fifth type

0.830(0.020)

0.007(0.002)

0.030(0.004)

0.133(0.018)

0.223(0.028)

0.194(0.038)

0.164(0.013)

0.418(0.043)

0.145(0.017)

0.056(0.016)

0.296(0.021)

0.503(0.034)

0.093(0.011)

0.025(0.009)

0.104(0.009)

0.778(0.023)

Note: bootstrapped standard errors are reported in parentheses.

25

Page 27: Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques G 2008 / 10

Table 9 Limiting Probabilities

Men SJ UJ U NP

Type 1 0.008(0.014)

0.006(0.002)

0.009(0.005)

0.977(0.017)

Type 2 0.998(0.001)

0.000(0.000)

0.001(0.000)

0.001(0.000)

Type 3 0.386(0.049)

0.492(0.040)

0.097(0.010)

0.025(0.004)

Type 4 0.154(0.042)

0.114(0.012)

0.658(0.038)

0.075(0.010)

Type 5 0.650(0.107)

0.007(0.088)

0.108(0.041)

0.234(0.056)

Women SJ UJ U NP

Type 1 0.000(0.003)

0.000(0.001)

0.003(0.002)

0.997(0.005)

Type 2 0.998(0.001)

0.000(0.000)

0.001(0.000)

0.001(0.000)

Type 3 0.247(0.035)

0.600(0.031)

0.117(0.007)

0.036(0.003)

Type 4 0.176(0.025)

0.087(0.008)

0.640(0.022)

0.097(0.009)

Type 5 0.384(0.049)

0.025(0.009)

0.096(0.009)

0.495(0.051)

Note: each row sums to one. Bootstrapped standard errors are reported in parentheses.

This alternative analysis does support the relevance of the mover-stayer-confined partition. First,

nonparticipant stayers and stayers in stable jobs appear clearly. Resultsare less clear-cut for the mover

categories, since individuals of all categories have a chance to obtain a stable job. This could be a

consequence of the structure imposed by the model. But for two types, probabilities to obtain a stable

job turns out to be rather small. Hence the results obtained here underline that clear differences exist in

the transition dynamics, and that splitting movers into confined/unconfined categories is relevant.

5.2. Specification tests: stability of transition matricesacross gender

In section 4 we focused on the results of separate estimations on sub-samples by gender. This was

justified by the results of the present section, in which we test whether, once controlling for conditional

heterogeneity, the transition dynamics on the labor market are the same for menand women. To do this,

we consider three testing hypotheses.

• H10 : both confined and unconfined-mover transition matrices are stable across gender,

• H20 : the unconfined-mover transition matrix is stable across gender,

• H30 : the confined-mover transition matrix is stable across gender.

H10 can be tested by a classical LR test: we estimate the model on men and women separately (M1)

and simultaneously with adequate covariates (M0), and compute a LR statistic. For testingH20 andH3

0 ,

we use aχ2-statistic (denotedDA, hereafter) based on the difference of the estimates between the two

26

Page 28: Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques G 2008 / 10

Table 10. Tests for stability of dynamics across gender (p-values).

Null hypothesis H10 H2

0 H30

30-49 0.000 0.000 0.513Note: Test statistics LR is the first column and DA for the second and the thirdones. p-values are computed usingχ2 distributions. Degrees of freedom areresp. 18 (24 and 12) for the first (second and third) columns.

groups which are assumed to be independent (the method is described in details in appendix B). Results

are reported in Table 10. The stability of the labor market dynamics across gender is rejected due to

different unconfined-mover dynamics whereas the stability of the confined-mover dynamics cannot be

rejected. For the latter, labor market histories differences can be explained conditionally, by differences

in covariates.

6. Conclusion

The model used in this paper is based on a Markov-chain mixture of four types of transition dynamics:

the stayers in stable-jobs, the stayers in nonparticipation, the unconfined movers, and the individuals

stuck onconfinedstates and who cannot accede to stable jobs. This partition enables us to specifically

account for heterogenous abilities to accede to stable jobs. The probabilities of being of a given type also

depend on observable individual characteristics. The data come from the French Labor Force Survey, the

model is estimated on the 30-49 years old individuals.

The main results are the following. Individuals who are trapped in confinedmover histories represent

around 5% of the 30-49 years old population (versus 13% apparently observed). At equilibrium, partic-

ipation rates of the confined and the unconfined populations are similar but an individual whose labor

market history is generated by the confined mover process has between 3and 4 times more chances to be

unemployed than a confined mover. The probability to be a confined mover decreases with the education

level. Male confined movers are also more likely to be single, and to live in a distressed area whereas

for women, only the education seems to matter. Finally, unconfined-mover dynamics depend on gender,

whereas male and female confined mover dynamics are not significantly different.

27

Page 29: Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques G 2008 / 10

APPENDIX

A. Stationary occupation probabilities

Confined-unconfined models, just like mover-stayer models, satisfy the Markov assumption conditional

on the initial state. The stationary occupation probability vector represents the probabilities associated

to each state once the process converged to the steady state and can be defined for any Markov-chain

process. Let us consider a Markov-chain process with transition matrixA. The stationary occupation

probability vector, denoteda∗, is defined such that it is invariant by pre-multiplication by the transition

matrix:

A′a∗ = a∗. (A.5)

Moreover, it is a vector of probabilities. Hence, its components remain in[0, 1] and sum to one. The

stationary occupation probability vector is a useful tool to describe how much labor market histories

generated by a given dynamic are confined in some states.

Stationary occupation probabilities (conditional on the initial values) are easily extended to mixtures

of Markov chains by:

pMm∗ + pQq∗ + pS1s∗1 + pSK s∗K ,

wherem∗, q∗, s∗1 and s∗K are the stationary probability vectors (as defined in A.5) relating to each

elementary Markov chain, andpM , pQ, pS1 , andpSK , the mixture coefficients relating to each elementary

Markov chain. In the conditional confined-unconfined model, sample stationary occupation probability

vector can be estimated by the sample average of the weighted sum of the stationary probability vectors

of each elementary Markov process composing the mixture.

1

N

N∑

i=1

pMi m∗ + p

Qi q∗ + pS1

i s∗1 + pSK

i s∗K ,

wherem∗, q∗, s∗1 and s∗K are the stationary probability vectors (as defined in A.5) relating to each

elementary Markov chain, andpMi , p

Qi , pS1

i , andpSK

i , the individual probabilities of following each

elementary Markov chain. Note thatpMi , p

Qi , pS1

i , pSK

i sum to one.

28

Page 30: Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques G 2008 / 10

B. Darmois-type test for coefficient equality across subsamples

The idea is the same as the the classical Darmois test for testing the equality of themeans in two sub-

samples with unknown different variances; see Darmois (1954). Data is composed of two samples:

sample 1, withn1 observations{Y1i }i=1,...,n1

whose distribution is function of the parameter of in-

terestβ1 ∈ Rk; and sample 2, withn2 observations{Y2

i }i=1,...,n2whose distribution is function of

β2 ∈ Rk. {Y1

i }i=1,...,n1and{Y2

i }i=1,...,n2are independent and both composed ofi.i.d. observations.̂β1

(resp. β̂2) denotes the estimate ofβ1 (resp. β2) based on sample 1 (resp. sample 2). Consider testing

H0 : β1 = β2 = β0 againstH1 : β1 6= β2. Assume that CLT theorems apply forβ1 andβ2, i.e. under

H0:

√n1(β̂1 − β0) → N (0, Vas(β̂1)) (B.6)

√n2(β̂2 − β0) → N (0, Vas(β̂2)) (B.7)

andβ̂1 andβ̂2 are independent. Hence, it follows that underH0,

DA = (β̂1 − β̂2)′

(

1

n1Vas(β̂1) +

1

n2Vas(β̂2)

)−1

(β̂1 − β̂2) → χ2(2k). (B.8)

A test forH0 with asymptotic levelα rejectsH0 whenDA > c1−α, wherec1−α is the 1-α quantile of a

χ2 distribution with2k degrees of freedom.

C. Detailed results

C.1. Women between 30 and 49

Women between 30 and 49, 4 states : out of the labor market (4), unemployed (3), short-term contract (2),

long-term contract (1). Asymptotic standard-errors are obtained by bootstrap (design matrix bootstrap

centered around the sample estimate) with 100 sample replicates.

Table 11 describes the observed histories.

29

Page 31: Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques G 2008 / 10

Table 11. Data : women between 30 and 49.Individuals... 17,359 100%staying in 1 10,495 60 %staying in 4 2,188 13%moving between 1, 2, 3 and 4 2,065 12%moving between 2, 3 and 4 only 2,611 15%

Figure 1. Densities of individual probabilities of being stayer in 1, stayer in4 and confined conditionalon initial states

0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 10

1

2

3

4

5

Bandwiths: kst1

=kst4

=kins

=0.02

Den

sitie

s

stayer 1 (| state1=1) stayer 4 (| state1=4) insecure (| state1=2,3,4)

C.2. Men between 30 and 49

Men between 30 and 49, 4 states : out of the labor market (4), unemployed(3), short-term contract (2),

long-term contract (1). Asymptotic standard-errors are obtained by bootstrap (design matrix bootstrap

centered around the sample estimate) with 100 sample replicates.

Table 14 describes the observed histories.

30

Page 32: Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques G 2008 / 10

Table 12. Coefficients: women between 30 and 49.Estimates - MLE

Covariates confined mover stayer in stable job stayer in non-participationintercept -1.244 0.931 -1.187

(1.409) (0.359) (0.626)30-39 - - -

- - -40-49 0.124 0.640 0.576

(0.179) (0.101) (0.108)married -0.234 0.125 0.627

(0.188) (0.096) (0.096)university degree 0.386 0.172 -0.453(bac+3 and more) (0.357) (0.218) (0.211)college degree or more 0.141 0.174 -0.229(bac+2 and more) (0.475) (0.172) (0.213)completed high school - - -(bac) - - -basic vocational degree 0.622 -0.359 0.096

(0.299) (0.142) (0.141)elementary high school 0.236 0.054 0.504

(0.380) (0.211) (0.165)no degree 1.081 -0.994 0.835

(0.326) (0.139) (0.154)ZUS 0.262 -0.421 0.190

(0.385) (0.231) (0.121)Paris -0.416 -0.153 -0.312

(0.288) (0.135) (0.135)one 0-18 year-old child or more 0.258 -0.154 -0.395

(0.205) (0.104) (0.111)one 3- 6 year-old child or more -0.038 -0.601 0.607

(0.643) (0.155) (0.137)one 0- 3 year-old child or more -0.114 -0.282 -0.365

(0.252) (0.126) (0.121)Experience above 7 years -0.636 0.397 0.905

(1.336) (0.307) ( 0.632)Average conditional 0.153 0.771 0.610probability (0.033) (0.014) (0.012)

Asymptotic standard errors estimates are obtained by design matrix bootstrap centered around the sample estimate with 100

sample replicates.

31

Page 33: Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques G 2008 / 10

Table 13. Transition matrices: women between 30 and 49.

Unconfined transition matrix:

T → T + 1 SJ UJ U NPSJ (k = 1) 0.931 0.011 0.023 0.036

(0.005) (0.001) (0.002) (0.003)UJ (k = 2) 0.079 0.836 0.061 0.023

(0.006) (0.033) (0.024) (0.008)U (k = 3) 0.082 0.099 0.720 0.099

(0.009) (0.025) (0.030) (0.019)NP (k = 4) 0.133 0.029 0.113 0.724

(0.014) (0.008) (0.016) (0.019)boot. st. err. : 100 replicates

Confined transition matrix:

T → T + 1 SJ UJ U NPSJ (k = 1) 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000

0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000UJ (k = 2) 0.000 0.600 0.302 0.098

0.000 (0.090) (0.074) (0.025)U (k = 3) 0.000 0.227 0.540 0.233

0.000 (0.076) (0.070) (0.058)NP(k = 4) 0.000 0.094 0.320 0.586

0.000 (0.080) (0.063) (0.096)boot. st. err. : 100 replicates

Stationary equilibria:

SJ UJ U UNPUnconfined equilibrium 0.585 0.143 0.134 0.138

(0.023) (0.009) (0.011) (0.013)Confined equilibrium 0.000 0.299 0.403 0.297

(0.000) (0.059) (0.044) (0.069)Total equilibrium 0.698 0.062 0.064 0.177

(0.004) (0.002) (0.002) (0.003)boot. st. err. : 100 replicates

32

Page 34: Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques G 2008 / 10

Table 14. Data : men between 30 and 49.Individuals... 15,847 100%staying in 1 12,497 79%staying in 4 382 2%moving between 1, 2, 3 and 4 1,571 10%moving between 2, 3 and 4 only 1,397 9%

Figure 2. Densities of individual probabilities of being stayer in 1, stayer in4 and confined conditionalon initial states

0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 10

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

Bandwiths: kst1

=kst4

=kins

=0.03

Den

sitie

s

stayer 1 (| state1=1) stayer 4 (| state1=4) insecure (| state1=2,3,4)

33

Page 35: Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques G 2008 / 10

Table 15. Coefficients: men between 30 and 49.Estimates - MLE

Covariates confined mover stayer in stable job stayer in non-participationintercept -0.480 1.141 0.892

(3.666) (0.391) (0.826)30-39 - - -

- - -40-49 0.028 0.475 0.832

(0.233) (0.094) (0.182)married -0.870 0.347 0.038

(0.245) (0.096) (0.209)university degree -0.019 0.089 -0.146(bac+3 and more) (1.930) (0.175) (0.415)college degree or more 0.270 0.306 -0.281(bac+2 and more) (0.484) (0.243) (0.446)completed high school - - -(bac) - - -basic vocational degree 0.361 -0.145 0.179

(0.447) (0.146) (0.306)elementary high school 1.257 -0.049 0.481

(0.616) (0.220) (0.353)no degree 1.391 -0.448 0.784

(0.486) (0.162) (0.314)ZUS 0.872 -0.644 0.312

(0.311) (0.211) (0.285)Paris -0.564 -0.123 -0.210

(0.494) (0.132) (0.332)one 0-18 year-old child or more -0.957 -0.062 -1.053

(0.253) (0.108) (0.225)one 0- 3 year-old child or more 0.069 0.057 -0.312

(0.374) (0.138) (0.408)Experience above 7 years -0.187 0.216 -1.108

(3.533) (0.370) (0.747)Average conditional 0.285 0.832 0.546probability (0.043) (0.012) (0.018)

Asymptotic standard errors estimates are obtained by design matrix bootstrap centered around the sample estimate with 100

sample replicates.

34

Page 36: Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques G 2008 / 10

Table 16. Transition matrices: men between 30 and 49.

Unconfined transition matrix:

T → T + 1 SJ UJ U NPSJ (k = 1) 0.934 0.014 0.029 0.023

(0.005) (0.001) (0.002) (0.002)UJ (k = 2) 0.115 0.800 0.069 0.016

(0.011) (0.032) (0.028) (0.005)U (k = 3) 0.118 0.136 0.670 0.076

(0.012) (0.025) (0.024) (0.009)NP (k = 4) 0.256 0.045 0.197 0.502

(0.023) (0.012) (0.020) (0.030)boot. st. err.: 100 replicates

Confined transition matrix:

T → T + 1 SJ UJ U NPSJ (k = 1) 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)UJ (k = 2) 0.000 0.650 0.286 0.064

(0.000) (0.098) (0.091) (0.016)U (k = 3) 0.000 0.163 0.729 0.108

(0.000) (0.052) (0.044) (0.018)NP(k = 4) 0.000 0.077 0.378 0.545

(0.000) (0.037) (0.065) (0.079)boot. st. err.: 100 replicates

Stationary equilibria:

SJ UJ U UNPUnconfined equilibrium 0.680 0.143 0.122 0.055

(0.026) (0.012) (0.014) (0.006)Confined equilibrium 0.000 0.289 0.541 0.169

(0.000) (0.054) (0.042) (0.032)Total equilibrium 0.860 0.045 0.051 0.045

(0.003) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002)boot. st. err.: 100 replicates

35

Page 37: Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques G 2008 / 10

References

ANDERSON, T., AND L. GOODMAN (1957): “Statistical Inference about Markov Chains,”Annals of

Mathematical Statistics, 28(1), 89–110.

ATTAL -TOUBERT, K., AND H. LAVERGNE (2006): “Premiers résultats de l’enquête sur l’emploi 2005,”

Insee-Premiere, 1070.

BEHAGHEL, L. (2003): “Insécurité de l’emploi: le rôle protecteur de l’ancienneté a-t-il baissé en

France?,”Economie et Statistiques, 366(1), 3–29.

BLANCHARD , O., AND A. L ANDIER (2002): “The Perverse Effects of Partial Labour Market Reform:

Fixed-Term Contracts in France,”The Economic Journal, 112, F214–F244.

BLUMEN , I., M. KOGAN, AND P. MACCARTHY (1955): The industrial mobility of labour as a proba-

bility process, no. 6 in Cornell Studies of Industrial and Labour Relations. Cornell University Press.

BONNAL , L., D. FOUGÈRE, AND A. SÉRANDON (1997): “Evaluating the Impact of French Employment

Policies on Individual Labour Market Histories,”Review of Economic Studies, 64, 683–713.

BRODATY, T. (2007): “Earnings Mobility, State Dependence and Unobserved Heterogeneity: the Case

of the United-State in the 90’s,” Crest, WP.

BURDETT, K. (1978): “A theory of employee job search and quit rates,”American Economic Review,

68(1), 212–220.

CAHUC, P.,AND F. POSTEL-V INAY (2002): “Temporary Jobs, Employment Protection and Labor Mar-

ket Performance,”Labour Economics, 9(1), 63–91.

CARD, D., AND D. SULLIVAN (1988): “Measuring the Effect of Subsidized Training Programs on

Movement In and Out of Employment,”Econometrica, 56, 497–530.

DARMOIS, G. (1954): “Comparaison des moyennes de deux populations normales d’écarts-types incon-

nus et différents. Test de Darmois,”Revue de statistique appliquée, 2(3), 37–41.

DOERINGHER, P., AND M. PIORE (1971): Internal labour markets and manpower analysis. Heath,

Lexington, Massachussetts.

36

Page 38: Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques G 2008 / 10

FLINN , C. J.,AND J. J. HECKMAN (1983): “Are unemployment and out of the labor force behaviorally

distinct labor force states?,”Journal of Labor Economics, 1(1), 28–42.

FOUGÈRE, D., AND T. KAMIONKA (1992a): “Mobilité et précarisation sur le marché français du travail :

une analyse longitudinale pour les années 1986 à 1988,”Economie et Prévision, 102-103.

(1992b): “Un modèle markovien du marché du travail,”Annales d’Economie et de Statistique,

27.

(2003): “Bayesian inference for the mover-stayer model in continuoustime with an application

to labour market transition data,”Journal of Applied Econometrics, 18.

(2008):The Econometrics of Panel Data,chap. 25. Springer.

FRYDMAN , H. (1984): “Maximum Likelihood Estimation in the Mover-Stayer Model,”Journal of the

American Statistical Association, 79(387).

GAZIER, B., AND H. PETIT (2007): “French labour market segmentation and French labour market

policies since the seventies : connecting changes,”Economie et Sociétés, 28(6), 1027–1056.

GEWEKE, J., R. MARSHALL , AND G. ZARKIN (1986a): “Exact inference for continuous time Markov

chain models,”Review of Economics Studies, 53(4), 653–669.

(1986b): “Mobility indices in Continuous Time Markov chain models,”Econometrica, 54(6),

1407–1423.

GIVORD, P.,AND E. MAURIN (2003): “Changes in job securities and their causes: an empirical analysis

for France, 1982-2002,”European Economic Review, 48(1), 595–615.

GOODMAN, L. (1961): “Statistical methods for the mover-stayer model,”Journal of the American Sta-

tistical Association, 56(296), 841–868.

HAVET, N. (2006): “L’insertion professionnelle des jeunes et mesures publiques : des trajectoires dif-

férenciées entre hommes et femmes,”Annales d’Economie et de Statistiques, 81, 225–250.

HECKMAN , J. J., AND B. SINGER (1984): “A Method for Minimizing the Impact of Distributional

Assumptions in Econometric Models for Duration Data,”Econometrica, 52, 271–320.

37

Page 39: Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques G 2008 / 10

JONES, S. R. G.,AND W. C. RIDDEL (2006): “Unemployment and Nonemployment: Heterogeneities

on Labor Market States,”Review of Economics and Statistics, 88, 314–323.

JOVANOVIC , B. (1979a): “Firm-specific capital and turnover,”Journal of Political Economy, 87(6),

1246–1260.

(1979b): “Job matching and the theory of turnover,”Journal of Political Economy, 87(5), 972–

990.

KALBFLEISH, J.,AND J. LAWLESS (1985): “The Analysis of Panel Data under a Markov Assumption,”

JASA, 80(392), 863–871.

KAMIONKA , T. (1996): “Heterogeneity and transition models,” mimeo, CNRS, GREMAQ.

KATZ , L. (1986): “Efficiency Wages Theories: a Partial Evaluation,” working paper 1906, NBER

Macroeconomics Annual.

L’H ORTY, Y. (2004): “Instabilité de l’emploi : quelles ruptures de tendance?,” document de recherche

04-01, Centre d’Etude des Politiques Economiques de l’Université d’Evry.

L INDBECK, A., AND D. J. SNOWER (1986): “Wage Setting, Unemployment, and Insider-Outsider Re-

lations,”American Economic Review, 76, 235–239.

(2002): “The Insider-Outsider Theory: A Survey,” IZA DiscussionPaper 534.

MAGNAC, T. (2000): “Subsidised training and youth employment: distinguishing unobserved hetero-

geneity from state dependence in labour market histories,”The Economic Journal, 110.

MAGNAC, T., AND J.-M. ROBIN (1994): “An econometric analysis of labour market transitions using

discrete and tenure data,”Labour Economics, 1.

MORTENSEN, D. (1988): “Wages, separations, and job tenure: on the job specific training or matching?,”

Journal of Labor Economics, 6(4), 445–471.

SINGER, B., AND S. SPILERMAN (1976): “The Representation of Social Processes by Markov Models,”

American Journal of Sociology, 82(1), 1–54.

SPENCE, A. M. (1973): “Job Market Signaling,”The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 87(3), 355–74.

38

Page 40: Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques G 2008 / 10

SPILERMAN, S. (1972): “Extension of the mover-stayer model,”American Journal of Sociology, 78(3),

599–626.

TOPEL, R., AND M. WARD (1992): “Job Mobility and the Careers of Young Men,”The Quarterly

Journal of Economics, pp. 439–479.

WILLIAMSON , O. (1975):Markets and Hierarchies. Free Press, New-York.

39

Page 41: Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques G 2008 / 10

G 9001 J. FAYOLLE et M. FLEURBAEY Accumulation, profitabilité et endettement des entreprises

G 9002 H. ROUSSE Détection et effets de la multicolinéarité dans les modèles linéaires ordinaires - Un prolongement de la réflexion de BELSLEY, KUH et WELSCH

G 9003 P. RALLE et J. TOUJAS-BERNATE Indexation des salaires : la rupture de 1983

G 9004 D. GUELLEC et P. RALLE Compétitivité, croissance et innovation de produit

G 9005 P. RALLE et J. TOUJAS-BERNATE Les conséquences de la désindexation. Analyse dans une maquette prix-salaires

G 9101 Equipe AMADEUS Le modèle AMADEUS - Première partie -Présentation générale

G 9102 J.L. BRILLET Le modèle AMADEUS - Deuxième partie -Propriétés variantielles

G 9103 D. GUELLEC et P. RALLE Endogenous growth and product innovation

G 9104 H. ROUSSE Le modèle AMADEUS - Troisième partie - Le commerce extérieur et l'environnement international

G 9105 H. ROUSSE Effets de demande et d'offre dans les résultats du commerce extérieur manufacturé de la France au cours des deux dernières décennies

G 9106 B. CREPON Innovation, taille et concentration : causalités et dynamiques

G 9107 B. AMABLE et D. GUELLEC Un panorama des théories de la croissance endogène

G 9108 M. GLAUDE et M. MOUTARDIER Une évaluation du coût direct de l'enfant de 1979 à 1989

G 9109 P. RALLE et alii France - Allemagne : performances économiques comparées

G 9110 J.L. BRILLET Micro-DMS NON PARU

G 9111 A. MAGNIER Effets accélérateur et multiplicateur en France depuis 1970 : quelques résultats empiriques

G 9112 B. CREPON et G. DUREAU Investissement en recherche-développement : analyse de causalités dans un modèle d'accélé-rateur généralisé

G 9113 J.L. BRILLET, H. ERKEL-ROUSSE, J. TOUJAS-BERNATE "France-Allemagne Couplées" - Deux économies vues par une maquette macro-économétrique

G 9201 W.J. ADAMS, B. CREPON, D. ENCAOUA Choix technologiques et stratégies de dissuasion d'entrée

G 9202 J. OLIVEIRA-MARTINS, J. TOUJAS-BERNATE

Macro-economic import functions with imperfect competition - An application to the E.C. Trade

G 9203 I. STAPIC Les échanges internationaux de services de la France dans le cadre des négociations multila-térales du GATT Juin 1992 (1ère version) Novembre 1992 (version finale)

G 9204 P. SEVESTRE L'économétrie sur données individuelles-temporelles. Une note introductive

G 9205 H. ERKEL-ROUSSE Le commerce extérieur et l'environnement in-ternational dans le modèle AMADEUS (réestimation 1992)

G 9206 N. GREENAN et D. GUELLEC Coordination within the firm and endogenous growth

G 9207 A. MAGNIER et J. TOUJAS-BERNATE Technology and trade : empirical evidences for the major five industrialized countries

G 9208 B. CREPON, E. DUGUET, D. ENCAOUA et P. MOHNEN Cooperative, non cooperative R & D and optimal patent life

G 9209 B. CREPON et E. DUGUET Research and development, competition and innovation : an application of pseudo maximum likelihood methods to Poisson models with heterogeneity

G 9301 J. TOUJAS-BERNATE Commerce international et concurrence impar-faite : développements récents et implications pour la politique commerciale

G 9302 Ch. CASES Durées de chômage et comportements d'offre de travail : une revue de la littérature

G 9303 H. ERKEL-ROUSSE Union économique et monétaire : le débat économique

G 9304 N. GREENAN - D. GUELLEC / G. BROUSSAUDIER - L. MIOTTI Innovation organisationnelle, dynamisme tech-nologique et performances des entreprises

G 9305 P. JAILLARD Le traité de Maastricht : présentation juridique et historique

G 9306 J.L. BRILLET Micro-DMS : présentation et propriétés

G 9307 J.L. BRILLET Micro-DMS - variantes : les tableaux

G 9308 S. JACOBZONE Les grands réseaux publics français dans une perspective européenne

G 9309 L. BLOCH - B. CŒURE Profitabilité de l'investissement productif et transmission des chocs financiers

G 9310 J. BOURDIEU - B. COLIN-SEDILLOT Les théories sur la structure optimal du capital : quelques points de repère

Liste des documents de travail de la Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques

Page 42: Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques G 2008 / 10

ii

G 9311 J. BOURDIEU - B. COLIN-SEDILLOT Les décisions de financement des entreprises françaises : une évaluation empirique des théo-ries de la structure optimale du capital

G 9312 L. BLOCH - B. CŒURÉ Q de Tobin marginal et transmission des chocs financiers

G 9313 Equipes Amadeus (INSEE), Banque de France, Métric (DP) Présentation des propriétés des principaux mo-dèles macroéconomiques du Service Public

G 9314 B. CREPON - E. DUGUET Research & Development, competition and innovation

G 9315 B. DORMONT Quelle est l'influence du coût du travail sur l'emploi ?

G 9316 D. BLANCHET - C. BROUSSE Deux études sur l'âge de la retraite

G 9317 D. BLANCHET Répartition du travail dans une population hété-rogène : deux notes

G 9318 D. EYSSARTIER - N. PONTY AMADEUS - an annual macro-economic model for the medium and long term

G 9319 G. CETTE - Ph. CUNÉO - D. EYSSARTIER -J. GAUTIÉ Les effets sur l'emploi d'un abaissement du coût du travail des jeunes

G 9401 D. BLANCHET Les structures par âge importent-elles ?

G 9402 J. GAUTIÉ Le chômage des jeunes en France : problème de formation ou phénomène de file d'attente ? Quelques éléments du débat

G 9403 P. QUIRION Les déchets en France : éléments statistiques et économiques

G 9404 D. LADIRAY - M. GRUN-REHOMME Lissage par moyennes mobiles - Le problème des extrémités de série

G 9405 V. MAILLARD Théorie et pratique de la correction des effets de jours ouvrables

G 9406 F. ROSENWALD La décision d'investir

G 9407 S. JACOBZONE Les apports de l'économie industrielle pour définir la stratégie économique de l'hôpital public

G 9408 L. BLOCH, J. BOURDIEU, B. COLIN-SEDILLOT, G. LONGUEVILLE Du défaut de paiement au dépôt de bilan : les banquiers face aux PME en difficulté

G 9409 D. EYSSARTIER, P. MAIRE Impacts macro-économiques de mesures d'aide au logement - quelques éléments d'évaluation

G 9410 F. ROSENWALD Suivi conjoncturel de l'investissement

G 9411 C. DEFEUILLEY - Ph. QUIRION Les déchets d'emballages ménagers : une

analyse économique des politiques française et allemande

G 9412 J. BOURDIEU - B. CŒURÉ - B. COLIN-SEDILLOT Investissement, incertitude et irréversibilité Quelques développements récents de la théorie de l'investissement

G 9413 B. DORMONT - M. PAUCHET L'évaluation de l'élasticité emploi-salaire dépend-elle des structures de qualification ?

G 9414 I. KABLA Le Choix de breveter une invention

G 9501 J. BOURDIEU - B. CŒURÉ - B. SEDILLOT Irreversible Investment and Uncertainty : When is there a Value of Waiting ?

G 9502 L. BLOCH - B. CŒURÉ Imperfections du marché du crédit, investisse-ment des entreprises et cycle économique

G 9503 D. GOUX - E. MAURIN Les transformations de la demande de travail par qualification en France Une étude sur la période 1970-1993

G 9504 N. GREENAN Technologie, changement organisationnel, qua-lifications et emploi : une étude empirique sur l'industrie manufacturière

G 9505 D. GOUX - E. MAURIN Persistance des hiérarchies sectorielles de sa-laires: un réexamen sur données françaises

G 9505 D. GOUX - E. MAURIN Bis Persistence of inter-industry wages differentials: a

reexamination on matched worker-firm panel data

G 9506 S. JACOBZONE Les liens entre RMI et chômage, une mise en perspective NON PARU - article sorti dans Economie et Prévision n° 122 (1996) - pages 95 à 113

G 9507 G. CETTE - S. MAHFOUZ Le partage primaire du revenu Constat descriptif sur longue période

G 9601 Banque de France - CEPREMAP - Direction de la Prévision - Erasme - INSEE - OFCE Structures et propriétés de cinq modèles macro-économiques français

G 9602 Rapport d’activité de la DESE de l’année 1995

G 9603 J. BOURDIEU - A. DRAZNIEKS L’octroi de crédit aux PME : une analyse à partir d’informations bancaires

G 9604 A. TOPIOL-BENSAÏD Les implantations japonaises en France

G 9605 P. GENIER - S. JACOBZONE Comportements de prévention, consommation d’alcool et tabagie : peut-on parler d’une gestion globale du capital santé ? Une modélisation microéconométrique empirique

G 9606 C. DOZ - F. LENGLART Factor analysis and unobserved component models: an application to the study of French business surveys

G 9607 N. GREENAN - D. GUELLEC La théorie coopérative de la firme

Page 43: Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques G 2008 / 10

iii

G 9608 N. GREENAN - D. GUELLEC Technological innovation and employment reallocation

G 9609 Ph. COUR - F. RUPPRECHT L’intégration asymétrique au sein du continent américain : un essai de modélisation

G 9610 S. DUCHENE - G. FORGEOT - A. JACQUOT Analyse des évolutions récentes de la producti-vité apparente du travail

G 9611 X. BONNET - S. MAHFOUZ The influence of different specifications of wages-prices spirals on the measure of the NAIRU : the case of France

G 9612 PH. COUR - E. DUBOIS, S. MAHFOUZ, J. PISANI-FERRY The cost of fiscal retrenchment revisited: how strong is the evidence ?

G 9613 A. JACQUOT Les flexions des taux d’activité sont-elles seule-ment conjoncturelles ?

G 9614 ZHANG Yingxiang - SONG Xueqing Lexique macroéconomique Français-Chinois

G 9701 J.L. SCHNEIDER La taxe professionnelle : éléments de cadrage économique

G 9702 J.L. SCHNEIDER Transition et stabilité politique d’un système redistributif

G 9703 D. GOUX - E. MAURIN Train or Pay: Does it Reduce Inequalities to En-courage Firms to Train their Workers?

G 9704 P. GENIER Deux contributions sur dépendance et équité

G 9705 E. DUGUET - N. IUNG R & D Investment, Patent Life and Patent Value An Econometric Analysis at the Firm Level

G 9706 M. HOUDEBINE - A. TOPIOL-BENSAÏD Les entreprises internationales en France : une analyse à partir de données individuelles

G 9707 M. HOUDEBINE Polarisation des activités et spécialisation des départements en France

G 9708 E. DUGUET - N. GREENAN Le biais technologique : une analyse sur données individuelles

G 9709 J.L. BRILLET Analyzing a small French ECM Model

G 9710 J.L. BRILLET Formalizing the transition process : scenarios for capital accumulation

G 9711 G. FORGEOT - J. GAUTIÉ Insertion professionnelle des jeunes et processus de déclassement

G 9712 E. DUBOIS High Real Interest Rates: the Consequence of a Saving Investment Disequilibrium or of an in-sufficient Credibility of Monetary Authorities?

G 9713 Bilan des activités de la Direction des Etudes et Synthèses Economiques - 1996

G 9714 F. LEQUILLER Does the French Consumer Price Index Over-state Inflation?

G 9715 X. BONNET Peut-on mettre en évidence les rigidités à la baisse des salaires nominaux ? Une étude sur quelques grands pays de l’OCDE

G 9716 N. IUNG - F. RUPPRECHT Productivité de la recherche et rendements d’échelle dans le secteur pharmaceutique français

G 9717 E. DUGUET - I. KABLA Appropriation strategy and the motivations to use the patent system in France - An econometric analysis at the firm level

G 9718 L.P. PELÉ - P. RALLE Âge de la retraite : les aspects incitatifs du régime général

G 9719 ZHANG Yingxiang - SONG Xueqing Lexique macroéconomique français-chinois, chinois-français

G 9720 M. HOUDEBINE - J.L. SCHNEIDER Mesurer l’influence de la fiscalité sur la locali-sation des entreprises

G 9721 A. MOUROUGANE Crédibilité, indépendance et politique monétaire Une revue de la littérature

G 9722 P. AUGERAUD - L. BRIOT Les données comptables d’entreprises Le système intermédiaire d’entreprises Passage des données individuelles aux données sectorielles

G 9723 P. AUGERAUD - J.E. CHAPRON Using Business Accounts for Compiling National Accounts: the French Experience

G 9724 P. AUGERAUD Les comptes d’entreprise par activités - Le pas-sage aux comptes - De la comptabilité d’entreprise à la comptabilité nationale - A paraître

G 9801 H. MICHAUDON - C. PRIGENT Présentation du modèle AMADEUS

G 9802 J. ACCARDO Une étude de comptabilité générationnelle pour la France en 1996

G 9803 X. BONNET - S. DUCHÊNE Apports et limites de la modélisation « Real Business Cycles »

G 9804 C. BARLET - C. DUGUET - D. ENCAOUA - J. PRADEL The Commercial Sucess of Innovations An econometric analysis at the firm level in French manufacturing

G 9805 P. CAHUC - Ch. GIANELLA - D. GOUX - A. ZILBERBERG Equalizing Wage Differences and Bargaining Power - Evidence form a Panel of French Firms

G 9806 J. ACCARDO - M. JLASSI La productivité globale des facteurs entre 1975 et 1996

Page 44: Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques G 2008 / 10

iv

G 9807 Bilan des activités de la Direction des Etudes et Synthèses Economiques - 1997

G 9808 A. MOUROUGANE Can a Conservative Governor Conduct an Ac-comodative Monetary Policy ?

G 9809 X. BONNET - E. DUBOIS - L. FAUVET Asymétrie des inflations relatives et menus costs : tests sur l’inflation française

G 9810 E. DUGUET - N. IUNG Sales and Advertising with Spillovers at the firm level: Estimation of a Dynamic Structural Model on Panel Data

G 9811 J.P. BERTHIER Congestion urbaine : un modèle de trafic de pointe à courbe débit-vitesse et demande élastique

G 9812 C. PRIGENT La part des salaires dans la valeur ajoutée : une approche macroéconomique

G 9813 A.Th. AERTS L’évolution de la part des salaires dans la valeur ajoutée en France reflète-t-elle les évolutions individuelles sur la période 1979-1994 ?

G 9814 B. SALANIÉ Guide pratique des séries non-stationnaires

G 9901 S. DUCHÊNE - A. JACQUOT Une croissance plus riche en emplois depuis le début de la décennie ? Une analyse en compa-raison internationale

G 9902 Ch. COLIN Modélisation des carrières dans Destinie

G 9903 Ch. COLIN Evolution de la dispersion des salaires : un essai de prospective par microsimulation

G 9904 B. CREPON - N. IUNG Innovation, emploi et performances

G 9905 B. CREPON - Ch. GIANELLA Wages inequalities in France 1969-1992 An application of quantile regression techniques

G 9906 C. BONNET - R. MAHIEU Microsimulation techniques applied to inter-generational transfers - Pensions in a dynamic framework: the case of France

G 9907 F. ROSENWALD L’impact des contraintes financières dans la dé-cision d’investissement

G 9908 Bilan des activités de la DESE - 1998

G 9909 J.P. ZOYEM Contrat d’insertion et sortie du RMI Evaluation des effets d’une politique sociale

G 9910 Ch. COLIN - Fl. LEGROS - R. MAHIEU Bilans contributifs comparés des régimes de retraite du secteur privé et de la fonction publique

G 9911 G. LAROQUE - B. SALANIÉ Une décomposition du non-emploi en France

G 9912 B. SALANIÉ Une maquette analytique de long terme du marché du travail

G 9912 Ch. GIANELLA

Bis Une estimation de l’élasticité de l’emploi peu qualifié à son coût

G 9913 Division « Redistribution et Politiques Sociales » Le modèle de microsimulation dynamique DESTINIE

G 9914 E. DUGUET Macro-commandes SAS pour l’économétrie des panels et des variables qualitatives

G 9915 R. DUHAUTOIS Evolution des flux d’emplois en France entre 1990 et 1996 : une étude empirique à partir du fichier des bénéfices réels normaux (BRN)

G 9916 J.Y. FOURNIER Extraction du cycle des afffaires : la méthode de Baxter et King

G 9917 B. CRÉPON - R. DESPLATZ - J. MAIRESSE Estimating price cost margins, scale economies and workers’ bargaining power at the firm level

G 9918 Ch. GIANELLA - Ph. LAGARDE Productivity of hours in the aggregate production function: an evaluation on a panel of French firms from the manufacturing sector

G 9919 S. AUDRIC - P. GIVORD - C. PROST Evolution de l’emploi et des coûts par quali-fication entre 1982 et 1996

G 2000/01 R. MAHIEU Les déterminants des dépenses de santé : une approche macroéconomique

G 2000/02 C. ALLARD-PRIGENT - H. GUILMEAU - A. QUINET The real exchange rate as the relative price of nontrables in terms of tradables: theoretical investigation and empirical study on French data

G 2000/03 J.-Y. FOURNIER L’approximation du filtre passe-bande proposée par Christiano et Fitzgerald

G 2000/04 Bilan des activités de la DESE - 1999

G 2000/05 B. CREPON - F. ROSENWALD Investissement et contraintes de financement : le poids du cycle Une estimation sur données françaises

G 2000/06 A. FLIPO Les comportements matrimoniaux de fait

G 2000/07 R. MAHIEU - B. SÉDILLOT Microsimulations of the retirement decision: a supply side approach

G 2000/08 C. AUDENIS - C. PROST Déficit conjoncturel : une prise en compte des conjonctures passées

G 2000/09 R. MAHIEU - B. SÉDILLOT Equivalent patrimonial de la rente et souscription de retraite complémentaire

G 2000/10 R. DUHAUTOIS Ralentissement de l’investissement : petites ou grandes entreprises ? industrie ou tertiaire ?

G 2000/11 G. LAROQUE - B. SALANIÉ Temps partiel féminin et incitations financières à l’emploi

G2000/12 Ch. GIANELLA Local unemployment and wages

Page 45: Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques G 2008 / 10

v

G2000/13 B. CREPON - Th. HECKEL - Informatisation en France : une évaluation à partir de données individuelles - Computerization in France: an evaluation based on individual company data

G2001/01 F. LEQUILLER - La nouvelle économie et la mesure de la croissance du PIB - The new economy and the measure ment of GDP growth

G2001/02 S. AUDRIC La reprise de la croissance de l’emploi profite-t-elle aussi aux non-diplômés ?

G2001/03 I. BRAUN-LEMAIRE Evolution et répartition du surplus de productivité

G2001/04 A. BEAUDU - Th. HECKEL Le canal du crédit fonctionne-t-il en Europe ? Une étude de l’hétérogénéité des comportements d’investissement à partir de données de bilan agrégées

G2001/05 C. AUDENIS - P. BISCOURP - N. FOURCADE - O. LOISEL Testing the augmented Solow growth model : An empirical reassessment using panel data

G2001/06 R. MAHIEU - B. SÉDILLOT Départ à la retraite, irréversibilité et incertitude

G2001/07 Bilan des activités de la DESE - 2000

G2001/08 J. Ph. GAUDEMET Les dispositifs d’acquisition à titre facultatif d’annuités viagères de retraite

G2001/09 B. CRÉPON - Ch. GIANELLA Fiscalité, coût d’usage du capital et demande de facteurs : une analyse sur données individuelles

G2001/10 B. CRÉPON - R. DESPLATZ Evaluation des effets des dispositifs d’allégements de charges sociales sur les bas salaires

G2001/11 J.-Y. FOURNIER Comparaison des salaires des secteurs public et privé

G2001/12 J.-P. BERTHIER - C. JAULENT R. CONVENEVOLE - S. PISANI Une méthodologie de comparaison entre consommations intermédiaires de source fiscale et de comptabilité nationale

G2001/13 P. BISCOURP - Ch. GIANELLA Substitution and complementarity between capital, skilled and less skilled workers: an analysis at the firm level in the French manufacturing industry

G2001/14 I. ROBERT-BOBEE Modelling demographic behaviours in the French microsimulation model Destinie: An analysis of future change in completed fertility

G2001/15 J.-P. ZOYEM Diagnostic sur la pauvreté et calendrier de revenus : le cas du “Panel européen des ménages »

G2001/16 J.-Y. FOURNIER - P. GIVORD La réduction des taux d’activité aux âges extrêmes, une spécificité française ?

G2001/17 C. AUDENIS - P. BISCOURP - N. RIEDINGER Existe-t-il une asymétrie dans la transmission du prix du brut aux prix des carburants ?

G2002/01 F. MAGNIEN - J.-L. TAVERNIER - D. THESMAR Les statistiques internationales de PIB par habitant en standard de pouvoir d’achat : une analyse des résultats

G2002/02 Bilan des activités de la DESE - 2001

G2002/03 B. SÉDILLOT - E. WALRAET La cessation d’activité au sein des couples : y a-t-il interdépendance des choix ?

G2002/04 G. BRILHAULT - Rétropolation des séries de FBCF et calcul du

capital fixe en SEC-95 dans les comptes nationaux français

- Retropolation of the investment series (GFCF) and estimation of fixed capital stocks on the ESA-95 basis for the French balance sheets

G2002/05 P. BISCOURP - B. CRÉPON - T. HECKEL - N. RIEDINGER How do firms respond to cheaper computers? Microeconometric evidence for France based on a production function approach

G2002/06 C. AUDENIS - J. DEROYON - N. FOURCADE L’impact des nouvelles technologies de l’information et de la communication sur l’économie française - un bouclage macro-économique

G2002/07 J. BARDAJI - B. SÉDILLOT - E. WALRAET Évaluation de trois réformes du Régime Général d’assurance vieillesse à l’aide du modèle de microsimulation DESTINIE

G2002/08 J.-P. BERTHIER Réflexions sur les différentes notions de volume dans les comptes nationaux : comptes aux prix d’une année fixe ou aux prix de l’année précédente, séries chaînées

G2002/09 F. HILD Les soldes d’opinion résument-ils au mieux les réponses des entreprises aux enquêtes de conjoncture ?

G2002/10 I. ROBERT-BOBÉE Les comportements démographiques dans le modèle de microsimulation Destinie - Une comparaison des estimations issues des enquêtes Jeunes et Carrières 1997 et Histoire Familiale 1999

G2002/11 J.-P. ZOYEM La dynamique des bas revenus : une analyse des entrées-sorties de pauvreté

G2002/12 F. HILD Prévisions d’inflation pour la France

G2002/13 M. LECLAIR Réduction du temps de travail et tensions sur les facteurs de production

G2002/14 E. WALRAET - A. VINCENT - Analyse de la redistribution intragénérationnelle dans le système de retraite des salariés du privé - Une approche par microsimulation - Intragenerational distributional analysis in the french private sector pension scheme - A microsimulation approach

Page 46: Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques G 2008 / 10

vi

G2002/15 P. CHONE - D. LE BLANC - I. ROBERT-BOBEE Offre de travail féminine et garde des jeunes enfants

G2002/16 F. MAUREL - S. GREGOIR Les indices de compétitivité des pays : inter-prétation et limites

G2003/01 N. RIEDINGER - E.HAUVY Le coût de dépollution atmosphérique pour les entreprises françaises : Une estimation à partir de données individuelles

G2003/02 P. BISCOURP et F. KRAMARZ Création d’emplois, destruction d’emplois et internationalisation des entreprises industrielles françaises : une analyse sur la période 1986-1992

G2003/03 Bilan des activités de la DESE - 2002

G2003/04 P.-O. BEFFY - J. DEROYON - N. FOURCADE - S. GREGOIR - N. LAÏB - B. MONFORT Évolutions démographiques et croissance : une projection macro-économique à l’horizon 2020

G2003/05 P. AUBERT La situation des salariés de plus de cinquante ans dans le secteur privé

G2003/06 P. AUBERT - B. CRÉPON Age, salaire et productivité La productivité des salariés décline-t-elle en fin de carrière ?

G2003/07 H. BARON - P.O. BEFFY - N. FOURCADE - R. MAHIEU Le ralentissement de la productivité du travail au cours des années 1990

G2003/08 P.-O. BEFFY - B. MONFORT Patrimoine des ménages, dynamique d’allocation et comportement de consommation

G2003/09 P. BISCOURP - N. FOURCADE Peut-on mettre en évidence l’existence de rigidités à la baisse des salaires à partir de données individulles ? Le cas de la France à la fin des années 90

G2003/10 M. LECLAIR - P. PETIT Présence syndicale dans les firmes : quel impact sur les inégalités salariales entre les hommes et les femmes ?

G2003/11 P.-O. BEFFY - X. BONNET - M. DARRACQ-PARIES - B. MONFORT MZE: a small macro-model for the euro area

G2004/01 P. AUBERT - M. LECLAIR La compétitivité exprimée dans les enquêtes trimestrielles sur la situation et les perspectives dans l’industrie

G2004/02 M. DUÉE - C. REBILLARD La dépendance des personnes âgées : une projection à long terme

G2004/03 S. RASPILLER - N. RIEDINGER Régulation environnementale et choix de localisation des groupes français

G2004/04 A. NABOULET - S. RASPILLER Les déterminants de la décision d’investir : une approche par les perceptions subjectives des firmes

G2004/05 N. RAGACHE La déclaration des enfants par les couples non mariés est-elle fiscalement optimale ?

G2004/06 M. DUÉE L’impact du chômage des parents sur le devenir scolaire des enfants

G2004/07 P. AUBERT - E. CAROLI - M. ROGER New Techlologies, Workplace Organisation and the Age Structure of the Workforce: Firm-Level Evidence

G2004/08 E. DUGUET - C. LELARGE Les brevets accroissent-ils les incitations privées à innover ? Un examen microéconométrique

G2004/09 S. RASPILLER - P. SILLARD Affiliating versus Subcontracting: the Case of Multinationals

G2004/10 J. BOISSINOT - C. L’ANGEVIN - B. MONFORT Public Debt Sustainability: Some Results on the French Case

G2004/11 S. ANANIAN - P. AUBERT Travailleurs âgés, nouvelles technologies et changements organisationnels : un réexamen à partir de l’enquête « REPONSE »

G2004/12 X. BONNET - H. PONCET Structures de revenus et propensions différentes à consommer - Vers une équation de consommation des ménages plus robuste en prévision pour la France

G2004/13 C. PICART Évaluer la rentabilité des sociétés non financières

G2004/14 J. BARDAJI - B. SÉDILLOT - E. WALRAET Les retraites du secteur public : projections à l’horizon 2040 à l’aide du modèle de microsimulation DESTINIE

G2005/01 S. BUFFETEAU - P. GODEFROY Conditions de départ en retraite selon l’âge de fin d’études : analyse prospective pour les générations 1945 à1974

G2005/02 C. AFSA - S. BUFFETEAU L’évolution de l’activité féminine en France : une approche par pseudo-panel

G2005/03 P. AUBERT - P. SILLARD Délocalisations et réductions d’effectifs dans l’industrie française

G2005/04 M. LECLAIR - S. ROUX Mesure et utilisation des emplois instables dans les entreprises

G2005/05 C. L’ANGEVIN - S. SERRAVALLE Performances à l’exportation de la France et de l’Allemagne - Une analyse par secteur et destination géographique

G2005/06 Bilan des activités de la Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques - 2004

G2005/07 S. RASPILLER La concurrence fiscale : principaux enseigne-ments de l’analyse économique

G2005/08 C. L’ANGEVIN - N. LAÏB Éducation et croissance en France et dans un panel de 21 pays de l’OCDE

G2005/09 N. FERRARI Prévoir l’investissement des entreprises

Page 47: Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques G 2008 / 10

vii

Un indicateur des révisions dans l’enquête de conjoncture sur les investissements dans l’industrie.

G2005/10 P.-O. BEFFY - C. L’ANGEVIN Chômage et boucle prix-salaires : apport d’un modèle « qualiifés/peu qualifiés »

G2005/11 B. HEITZ A two-states Markov-switching model of inflation in France and the USA: credible target VS inflation spiral

G2005/12 O. BIAU - H. ERKEL-ROUSSE - N. FERRARI Réponses individuelles aux enquêtes de conjoncture et prévision macroéconomiques : Exemple de la prévision de la production manufacturière

G2005/13 P. AUBERT - D. BLANCHET - D. BLAU The labour market after age 50: some elements of a Franco-American comparison

G2005/14 D. BLANCHET - T. DEBRAND - P. DOURGNON - P. POLLET L’enquête SHARE : présentation et premiers résultats de l’édition française

G2005/15 M. DUÉE La modélisation des comportements démogra-phiques dans le modèle de microsimulation DESTINIE

G2005/16 H. RAOUI - S. ROUX Étude de simulation sur la participation versée aux salariés par les entreprises

G2006/01 C. BONNET - S. BUFFETEAU - P. GODEFROY Disparités de retraite de droit direct entre hommes et femmes : quelles évolutions ?

G2006/02 C. PICART Les gazelles en France

G2006/03 P. AUBERT - B. CRÉPON -P. ZAMORA Le rendement apparent de la formation continue dans les entreprises : effets sur la productivité et les salaires

G2006/04 J.-F. OUVRARD - R. RATHELOT Demographic change and unemployment: what do macroeconometric models predict?

G2006/05 D. BLANCHET - J.-F. OUVRARD Indicateurs d’engagements implicites des systèmes de retraite : chiffrages, propriétés analytiques et réactions à des chocs démographiques types

G2006/06 G. BIAU - O. BIAU - L. ROUVIERE Nonparametric Forecasting of the Manufacturing Output Growth with Firm-level Survey Data

G2006/07 C. AFSA - P. GIVORD Le rôle des conditions de travail dans les absences pour maladie

G2006/08 P. SILLARD - C. L’ANGEVIN - S. SERRAVALLE Performances comparées à l’exportation de la France et de ses principaux partenaires Une analyse structurelle sur 12 ans

G2006/09 X. BOUTIN - S. QUANTIN Une méthodologie d’évaluation comptable du coût du capital des entreprises françaises : 1984-2002

G2006/10 C. AFSA L’estimation d’un coût implicite de la pénibilité du travail chez les travailleurs âgés

G2006/11 C. LELARGE Les entreprises (industrielles) françaises sont-elles à la frontière technologique ?

G2006/12 O. BIAU - N. FERRARI Théorie de l’opinion Faut-il pondérer les réponses individuelles ?

G2006/13 A. KOUBI - S. ROUX Une réinterprétation de la relation entre productivité et inégalités salariales dans les entreprises

G2006/14 R. RATHELOT - P. SILLARD The impact of local taxes on plants location decision

G2006/15 L. GONZALEZ - C. PICART Diversification, recentrage et poids des activités de support dans les groupes (1993-2000)

G2007/01 D. SRAER Allègements de cotisations patronales et dynamique salariale

G2007/02 V. ALBOUY - L. LEQUIEN Les rendements non monétaires de l’éducation : le cas de la santé

G2007/03 D. BLANCHET - T. DEBRAND Aspiration à la retraite, santé et satisfaction au travail : une comparaison européenne

G2007/04 M. BARLET - L. CRUSSON Quel impact des variations du prix du pétrole sur la croissance française ?

G2007/05 C. PICART Flux d’emploi et de main-d’œuvre en France : un réexamen

G2007/06 V. ALBOUY - C. TAVAN Massification et démocratisation de l’enseignement supérieur en France

G2007/07 T. LE BARBANCHON The Changing response to oil price shocks in France : a DSGE type approach

G2007/08 T. CHANEY - D. SRAER - D. THESMAR Collateral Value and Corporate Investment Evidence from the French Real Estate Market

G2007/09 J. BOISSINOT Consumption over the Life Cycle: Facts for France

G2007/10 C. AFSA Interpréter les variables de satisfaction : l’exemple de la durée du travail

G2007/11 R. RATHELOT - P. SILLARD Zones Franches Urbaines : quels effets sur l’emploi salarié et les créations d’établissements ?

G2007/12 V. ALBOUY - B. CRÉPON Aléa moral en santé : une évaluation dans le cadre du modèle causal de Rubin

G2008/01 C. PICART Les PME françaises : rentables mais peu dynamiques

Page 48: Direction des Études et Synthèses Économiques G 2008 / 10

viii

G2008/02 P. BISCOURP - X. BOUTIN - T. VERGÉ The Effects of Retail Regulations on Prices Evidence form the Loi Galland

G2008/03 Y. BARBESOL - A. BRIANT Économies d’agglomération et productivité des entreprises : estimation sur données individuelles françaises

G2008/04 D. BLANCHET - F. LE GALLO Les projections démographiques : principaux mécanismes et retour sur l’expérience française

G2008/05 D. BLANCHET - F. TOUTLEMONDE Évolutions démographiques et déformation du cycle de vie active : quelles relations ?

G2008/06 M. BARLET - D. BLANCHET - L. CRUSSON Internationalisation et flux d’emplois : que dit une approche comptable ?

G2008/07 C. LELARGE - D. SRAER - D. THESMAR Entrepreurship and Credit Constraints - Evidence from a French Loan Guarantee Program

G2008/08 X. BOUTIN - L. JANIN Are Prices Really Affected by Mergers?

G2008/09 M. BARLET - A. BRIANT - L. CRUSSON Concentration géographique dans l’industrie manufacturière et dans les services en France : une approche par un indicateur en continu

G2008/10 M. BEFFY - É. COUDIN - R. RATHELOT Who is confronted to insecure labor market histories? Some evidence based on the French labor market transition